Economics HL
Economics HL
4
Chapters
117
Notes
Unit 1 - Intro To Econ & Core Concepts
Unit 1 - Intro To Econ & Core Concepts
Unit 2 - Microeconomics
Unit 2 - Microeconomics
Unit 3 - Macroeconomics
Unit 3 - Macroeconomics
Unit 4 - The Global Economy
Unit 4 - The Global Economy
IB Resources
Unit 2 - Microeconomics
Economics HL
Economics HL

Unit 2 - Microeconomics

Understanding Monopoly Firms Efficiency & Market Power

Word Count Emoji
684 words
Reading Time Emoji
4 mins read
Updated at Emoji
Last edited on 5th Nov 2024

Table of content

Key Concepts

  • Monopoly
  • Allocative efficiency
  • Technical efficiency
  • Marginal cost (MC)
  • Average revenue (AR)
  • Social surplus
  • Consumer and producer surplus
  • Lerner Index of Monopoly Power
  • Market power

Monopolies and efficiency

 Monopolies Are Allocatively Inefficient

Allocative efficiency is when goods and services are distributed optimally, meaning everyone gets exactly what they want. In a perfect world, the price we pay for a product would match the cost of producing one more unit of that product (marginal cost or MC). However, monopolies don't live in a perfect world.

 

Example: Let's say you're the only one in town selling unicorn frappuccinos. As a monopoly, you might charge $8 for each one (P), even though it only costs you $3 (MC) to make one more. This price exceeds the marginal cost, leading to allocative inefficiency.

 

 Monopolies Are Technically Inefficient

Unlike in a perfectly competitive market, monopolies aren't pressured to produce goods with the minimum average cost. It's like baking a cake and not worrying about using the cheapest ingredients because you're the only bakery around.

Perfect competition vs. monopoly

In a perfectly competitive market, the interaction of demand and supply leads to an equilibrium price and quantity. Monopolies, however, restrict output to raise prices, leading to less production and higher prices than in competitive markets.

 

Example: In the competitive market of teddy bears, the equilibrium price might be $10 with 1000 teddy bears sold. But if you held the teddy bear monopoly, you might only produce 700 teddy bears and sell each for $15, since there's no competition to stop you.

Unlock the Full Content! File Is Locked Emoji

Dive deeper and gain exclusive access to premium files of Economics HL. Subscribe now and get closer to that 45 🌟

Nail IB's App Icon
IB Resources
Unit 2 - Microeconomics
Economics HL
Economics HL

Unit 2 - Microeconomics

Understanding Monopoly Firms Efficiency & Market Power

Word Count Emoji
684 words
Reading Time Emoji
4 mins read
Updated at Emoji
Last edited on 5th Nov 2024

Table of content

Key Concepts

  • Monopoly
  • Allocative efficiency
  • Technical efficiency
  • Marginal cost (MC)
  • Average revenue (AR)
  • Social surplus
  • Consumer and producer surplus
  • Lerner Index of Monopoly Power
  • Market power

Monopolies and efficiency

 Monopolies Are Allocatively Inefficient

Allocative efficiency is when goods and services are distributed optimally, meaning everyone gets exactly what they want. In a perfect world, the price we pay for a product would match the cost of producing one more unit of that product (marginal cost or MC). However, monopolies don't live in a perfect world.

 

Example: Let's say you're the only one in town selling unicorn frappuccinos. As a monopoly, you might charge $8 for each one (P), even though it only costs you $3 (MC) to make one more. This price exceeds the marginal cost, leading to allocative inefficiency.

 

 Monopolies Are Technically Inefficient

Unlike in a perfectly competitive market, monopolies aren't pressured to produce goods with the minimum average cost. It's like baking a cake and not worrying about using the cheapest ingredients because you're the only bakery around.

Perfect competition vs. monopoly

In a perfectly competitive market, the interaction of demand and supply leads to an equilibrium price and quantity. Monopolies, however, restrict output to raise prices, leading to less production and higher prices than in competitive markets.

 

Example: In the competitive market of teddy bears, the equilibrium price might be $10 with 1000 teddy bears sold. But if you held the teddy bear monopoly, you might only produce 700 teddy bears and sell each for $15, since there's no competition to stop you.

Unlock the Full Content! File Is Locked Emoji

Dive deeper and gain exclusive access to premium files of Economics HL. Subscribe now and get closer to that 45 🌟